Solution Manual for Taxes and Business Strategy, 5th Edition
Solution Manual for Taxes and Business Strategy, 5th Edition simplifies the toughest textbook questions, providing easy-to-follow solutions for every chapter.
Owen Collins
Contributor
4.8
45
5 months ago
Preview (16 of 203 Pages)
100%
Purchase to unlock
Loading document content...
Preview Mode
Sign in to access the full document!
Solutions Manual Taxes and Business Strategy A Planning Approach Global Edition Fifth Edition Myron Scholes Mark Wolfson Merle Erickson Michelle Hanlon Ed Maydew Terry Shevlin 0 CONTENTS Chapter 1 Introduction to Tax Strategy 1 C hapter 2 Tax Law Fundamentals 8 Chapter 3 Returns on Alternative Savings Vehicles 18 Chapter 4 Choosing the Optimal Organizational Form 30 Chapter 5 Implicit Taxes and Clienteles, Arbitrage, Restrictions and Frictions 48 Chapter 6 Nontax Costs of Tax Planning 67 Chapter 7 The Importance of Marginal Tax Rates and Dynamic Tax Planning Considerations 82 Chapter 8 Compensation Planning 93 Chapter 9 Pension and Retirement Program Planning 107 Chapter 10 Multinational Tax Planning: Introduction and Investment Decisions 121 Chapter 11 Multinational Tax Planning: Foreign Tax Credit Limitations and Income Shifting 127 Chapter 12 Corporations: Formation, Operation, Capital Structure and Liquidation 133 Chapter 13 Introduction to Tax Planning for Mergers, Acquisitions and Divestitures 136 Chapter 14 Taxable Acquisitions of Freestanding C Corporations8 139 Chapter 15 Taxable Acquisitions of S Corporations 144 Chapter 16 Tax-Free Acquisitions of Freestanding C Corporations 151 Chapter 17 Tax Planning for Divestitures 162 Chapter 18 Estate and Gift Tax Planning 172 1 Chapter 1 Introduction to Tax Strategy Discussion Questions 1. a. This statement is correct since municipal bonds are tax-favored. b. This statement is not correct. For example, suppose (1) your tax rate is 30% and you can invest in municipal bonds that yield 10% or equally risky taxable bonds that yield 16%. You should invest in the taxables and pay explicit taxes of 4.8% to earn an after-tax return of 11.2% (which exceeds the 10% after- tax return on munis). c. This statement is correct when the business assets are eligible for favorable tax treatment to owners. This is the case in most countries. When owning is tax-favored, it gives rise to high implicit taxes. Low-tax-rate investors do not value the tax benefits as much as high-tax-rate investors do. The low- tax-rate investors can effectively sell the tax benefits to ownership by renting at reduced rental rates. d. This statement is not necessarily correct. Suppose that employers’ tax rates are going to fall more than employee tax rates. In this case, the tax benefit of deferral to employees may be swamped by the cost of deferral to the employer. By adjusting the level of current compensation, employees can be made to prefer current payment. Nontax considerations may also be important. To the extent employees have a strong preference for current consumption and they cannot borrow funds at favorable interest rates, current compensation may be preferred even when taxes can be saved by deferring compensation. We will analyze this problem more formally in chapter Eight. 2. After-tax rates of return are not always lower than pretax rates of return. For example, for a tax exempt municipal bond the after-tax rate of return equals the pretax rate of return. Consider also the following counter-example. The taxpayer invests $1,000 in some activity with the investment being immediately tax deductible. At the end of the year the activity gives rise to a gain of $800 taxed as a capital gain. The taxpayer faces a tax rate of 39.6% on ordinary income and 20% on capital gains. The pre-tax rate of return in this simple example is (800 – 1,000)/1,000 = -20%. The after-tax rate of return is [800(1-.20) – 1,000(1-.396)]/1,000(1-.396) = (640 – 604)/604 = 5.96%. 3. a. Revenue less cost of goods sold from operations, dividend and interest income, royalties, rental income. Similarly to individuals, all items of income are included in gross income from whatever source unless specifically excluded by the Tax Code. Generally appreciation in the value of assets held is not taxable until the gain is realized by sale or exchange of the asset. b. Tax exempt interest on municipal bonds. c. All expenses incurred in conducting the trade or business (§ 162). Depreciation of plant and buildings, wages and salaries, interest expense, rental expense, advertising and marketing expenses, research and development expenditures, charitable contributions (within limits), deductions for past tax 1 Chapter 1 Introduction to Tax Strategy losses (a net operating loss carryforward deduction), deduction for dividends received from other corporations (the dividend received deduction) and utilities. d. Research and development credit, foreign tax credits, the alternative minimum tax credit. 4. Tax avoidance is another label for effective tax planning. See the quote in the text attributed to Judge Learned Hand. The courts have upheld taxpayers’ rights to arrange their affairs in ways to maximize their after-tax rates of return, provided the arrangements are within the law. Tax evasion denotes activity that is outside the law such as not reporting income that is taxable, or falsely claiming or overstating deductions. Tax evasion represents fraudulent activity and is illegal. Tax evasion is also labeled as deliberate noncompliance. A taxpayer facing a high marginal tax rate who buys a tax-exempt municipal bond and thus faces no explicit taxes is practicing tax avoidance but a taxpayer who buys a taxable corporate bond but omits the interest income on his tax return is practicing tax evasion. 5. 1. When facing a business decision in which taxes play a role, a planner employing efficient tax planning considers all of the costs, tax and nontax, that will be incurred by all of the parties to the transaction. In addition to the explicit tax payments that will result from the transaction, the planner considers implicit taxes that parties will pay in the form of lower before-tax rates of return on tax-favored investments as well as any other non-tax costs associated with the transaction such as the costs of restructuring an organization to obtain favorable tax treatment. A planner whose criterion is tax minimization, on the other hand, ignores many of these costs. A tax minimizer considers only explicit tax costs. It is easy to see that such a criterion may not result in desirable business strategies when one considers that zero taxes are paid on unprofitable investments. 6. Social planners should encourage taxpayers to engage in costly tax planning when no alternative means of attaining the same social goals is less costly. For example, consider the social goal of providing low-income housing. A system of tax subsidies to providers of this housing may require some taxpayers to incur costs in considering the explicit taxes, implicit taxes, and nontax costs that would affect them and other parties if they were to build low-income housing. If the next-best alternative means of providing low-income housing is for the government to build it directly, the social costs associated with providing this housing may be higher. 7. Greater specificity in the law can only be achieved at the higher cost of drafting and legislating. Moreover, where it is expensive for the taxing authority to monitor taxpayers' affairs closely (in other words, in the real world) specific rules can provide greater opportunities for taxpayers to structure their affairs in a way that exploits the rules. Greater specificity in the rules would also impose greater burdens on taxpayers and the taxing authority in learning what the relevant rules are. Once learned, however, greater specificity in the rules would give rise to fewer disputes between taxpayers and the tax collectors regarding tax liabilities. 8. a. Salary and wages, interest and dividend income, gains on sale of securities (may qualify for favorable capital gains treatment). An individual’s income from operating a business is included in gross income after deducting the cost of good sold. All items of income are included in gross income from whatever source unless specifically excluded by the Tax Code. 2 Chapter 1 Introduction to Tax Strategy b. Municipal bond income is excluded from gross income (it is tax exempt). c. In calculating adjusted gross income, some items are deducted from gross income (called Deductions for AGI). Examples include trade or business expenses such as advertising, depreciation, etc for taxpayers operating a business. For employees, payments by the employer to reimburse the employee for certain expenses such as travel, transportation and entertainment expenses incurred by the employee are deductible. Moving expenses and losses from the sale or exchange of property are also classified as deductions for AGI. Next the taxpayer deducts the maximum of itemized deductions or the standard deduction and exemptions to arrive at taxable income. Itemized deductions are expenses of a personal nature which the Tax Code allows the taxpayer to deduct. Examples include home mortgage interest, property taxes, state and local income taxes, charitable contributions, and medical expenses above a certain limit. The total of itemized deductions is compared to the standard deduction (determined by the filing status of the taxpayer – single, married filing jointly, married filing separately, head of household, and surviving spouse) allowed by the Tax Code – the standard deduction is a fixed amount used to simplify the preparation of the tax return for taxpayers with relatively low itemized deductions. Finally each taxpayer is entitled to a personal exemption (provided the taxpayer is not eligible to be claimed as a dependent on another taxpayer’s return). d. A credit is a dollar-for-dollar reduction in the taxpayer’s tax liability (and thus is worth more than a deduction, because a deduction of $1 only reduces the tax liability by the taxpayer’s marginal tax rate). Examples of tax credits for individuals are the earned income credit, child tax credit, credit for elderly, dependent care credit, general business credit, and foreign tax credit (for individuals with foreign earnings and foreign taxes paid). (The reader interested in a more technical discussion is referred to any technical tax textbook.) 3 Chapter 1 Introduction to Tax Strategy 9. Shifting income is beneficial when a high-tax-rate taxpayer can shift before-tax income to a low- tax-rate taxpayer. One way this could be effected is for the low-tax-rate taxpayer to “sell” the right to reduced taxes to the high-tax-rate individual by setting the terms of trade accordingly. In the case of related parties, the shifting income may be accomplished without a quid pro quo. Shifting income can be costly in that it typically requires a distortion in asset ownership or control; or it can give rise to distorted patterns of cash flows over time. For example, one way to shift income from high-income to low-income taxpayers is for high-income taxpayers to own tax-sheltered assets, like residential property, that are leased to low-income taxpayers. Another example is the formation of a partnership, where low-tax-rate taxpayers are allocated most of the annual income and high-tax-rate taxpayers are allocated most of the appreciation in the value of the partnership (to be realized on sale or liquidation of the partnership). In each example, the parties' incentives can be affected in unfortunate ways. In family tax planning, one might transfer income-producing assets to a child with the intention that the earnings will pay for the child’s education. A risk, however, is that the child may drop out of school and spend the money foolishly. Another way to transfer income to a low-tax-rate family member is by employing them in a family business. To the extent the family member is ill-suited to the job, such a strategy exacts an efficiency cost. Under the assignment-of-income doctrine, taxpayers must transfer an income-producing asset to a low-tax-rate taxpayer in order to shift taxable income. Costs arise from the high-tax-rate individual not being able to control what the low-tax-rate individual does with the assets. One way to mitigate these costs is to transfer the assets to a trust and have the trustee manage the assets in a pre-specified manner. Exercises 1. Alternative A Alternative B Investment $20,000 $18,000 Expected Payoff $21,000 x .75 = $15,750 $25,000 x .80 = $20,000 Pretax rate of return (15,750-20,000)/20,000 = -21.25% (20,000 – 18,000)/18,000 = 11.11% After-tax rate of return* For taxpayer with 15% rate -7.35% 11.11% For taxpayer with 35% rate 21.15% 11.11% *Alternative A: after-tax rate of return calculation: (expected payoff – after-tax cost of investment)/after-tax cost of investment 4 Chapter 1 Introduction to Tax Strategy = (15,750 – 20,000[1-t])/20,000[1-t]. The expected payoffs represent tax savings which are tax- exempt. Alternative B: after-tax rate of return calculation: (expected after-tax payoff - after-tax cost of investment)/after-tax cost of investment = (20,000[1-t] – 18,000[1-t])/18,000[1-t] = 2,000[1-t]/18,000[1-t] = 2,000/18,000 = 11.11%. Since the payoff is ‘taxable’ (cost savings reduce the tax deduction) and the investment is tax deductible at the same tax rate, the after-tax rate of return equals the pre-tax rate of return. The low-tax bracket taxpayer should invest in alternative B because this maximizes her after-tax rate of return. The high-tax bracket taxpayer should invest in alternative A. And note that alternative A represents tax planning activity and while the pretax rate of return is negative, for the high-tax bracket taxpayer, the after-tax rate of return is positive and higher than alternative B. This example illustrates that tax planning is a tax-favored activity which activity is more valuable for high-tax bracket taxpayers. 2. Taxpayer A invests in corporate bonds: after-tax rate of return = .125(1-.28) = .09. Taxpayer B invests in tax-exempt municipal bonds: after-tax rate of return = .09. Thus both taxpayers are earning 9% per annum after-tax. Taxpayer B is not paying any explicit taxes but is paying implicit taxes in the form of a lower pre-tax rate of return compared to the 12.5% pretax rate of return on the fully taxable bond. a. The implicit taxes are being paid to the municipality issuing the tax-exempt bond. b. Taxpayer B is paying implicit taxes here at a rate of 28% (= [.125-.09]/.125). 3. If receive bonus now: after-tax amount received is $30,000(1-.396) = $18,120. The taxpayer can invest this amount to earn 5% after-tax for the year which will cumulate to $18,120(1.05) = $19,026 at the end of next year. If defer bonus for one year (assumed received at end of the next year, not at the start of the next year): after-tax amount received is $30,000(1-.31) = $20,700. Thus defer receipt of bonus for one year. However, if the taxpayer can earn 15% after-tax on her investment, then $30,000 received now will accumulate to $30,000(1-396)(1.15) = $20,838 which now exceeds the amount from the one-year deferral. 4. Price willing to pay for the corporate bond is $1,000 (the face value). The bond promises a coupon of 6% and the taxpayer requires a pretax rate of return of 6% as well. More formally Price = present value of the coupon payments + present value of the face amount (Pretax calculation): price = .06 x (1,000) x PVA + $1,000 x PV1 where PVA is the present value of a $1 annuity for 5 years at 6% per annum = 4.212, and PV1 = is the present value of a dollar to be received in 5 years at 6% per annum = .747. Thus .06 x (1,000) x 4.212 + 1,000 x .747 = $1,000. (On an after-tax basis): price = [.06 x (1,000)](1-t) x PVA + $1,000 x PV1 where the PVA and PV1 factors use an after-tax discount rate .06[1-.31] = .0414 implying a PVA factor of 4.434 and PV1 of .8164. Thus, 5 Chapter 1 Introduction to Tax Strategy Price = [.06 x (1,000)](1-.31) x 4.434 + $1,000 x .8164 = $1,000. Price willing to pay for the municipal bond. Since the taxpayer can earn 4.14% after-tax by investing in the fully taxable bond, he requires this as a minimum rate of return on the muni and thus is willing to pay a maximum of Price = .06 x (1,000) x PVA + $1,000 x PV1 where PVA and PV1 are based on the after-tax discount rate of 4.14%. Thus Price = .06 x (1,000) x 4.434 + $1,000 x .8164 = $1,082.44. The taxpayer is indifferent between the fully taxable bond at a price of $1,000 and the tax-exempt municipal bond at a price of $1,082.44 because at these prices both offer an after-tax rate of return of 4.14%. This example relates to implicit taxes because the taxpayer is willing to pay more for the tax favored treatment of the municipal bond thus lowering its pretax (also equal to after-tax) rate of return. The implicit tax is the difference between the 6% pretax return on the fully taxable bond and the 4.14% pretax rate of return on the muni. The implicit tax rate is 31% [(.06 - .0414)/.06]. 6 Chapter 1 Introduction to Tax Strategy Tax Planning Problems 1. If the CEOs’ actions or available projects from which she can choose are unobservable to the compensation committee (a hidden information problem which is discussed in more detail in chapter 6, but which problem is common in large corporations) then the CEO has to be offered incentives to choose those projects which maximizes the value of the firm (rather than maximizes the utility of the CEO). One solution is to tie part of the CEO’s compensation to the payoffs (either accounting earnings or stock price) – this is what bonuses as a function of reported earnings and employee stock options are intended to do. If the CEO is about to retire and is facing investment decisions that require large current outlays with large future expected payoffs, the firm is said to face an horizon problem: the CEO is looking at short-term results when the firm’s shareholders would rather a long-term focus. Again some sort of compensation package (say restricted stock or deferred bonus) that links compensation to the deferred outcomes might be desirable. Oftentimes the CEO has much wealth (human capital and money) tied to the firm and is thus likely to be more risk averse than shareholders who are likely to hold diversified portfolios. Thus risk averse CEOs might forgo risky but positive net present value projects. Again the compensation package might include components (such as employee stock options that increase in value as the risk of the firm increases) that encourage increased risk taking by the CEO. The firm in designing the compensation package thus must not only consider taxes but also what incentives the compensation package might offer the CEO. Oftentimes, the CEO’s compensation package is designed with incentive alignment as the first priority and taxes as the second priority. We will discuss this issue in more detail in Chapter Six. 2. First note that a firm with accumulated tax losses can carryforward these losses and deduct them against future taxable income. Traditionally, we think of firms with net operating loss carryforwards as facing lower marginal tax rates than a firm currently earning income (discussed in more detail in Chapter Seven). Plan A: borrow and purchase the plant. Not very tax efficient because will not be deducting the interest on the borrowing at high corporate tax rate nor will the depreciation deductions on the plant be taken at the highest tax rates. Plan B: issue equity and buy the plant. Issuing equity is tax efficient for low tax firms but buying the plant is not, for reasons given above. Plan C: leasing is likely the most tax efficient. Once we analyze the tax positions of both low tax- bracket and high tax-bracket taxpayers, we might find low tax-bracket taxpayers better off passing up tax savings and renting. The reason is that low tax-bracket and high tax-bracket businesses will find it desirable to enter into a contract that arranges property rights so that the low tax-bracket businesses effectively sell their tax benefits to high tax-bracket businesses. This is accomplished by reducing the 7 Chapter 1 Introduction to Tax Strategy rental rate to the low tax-bracket taxpayer in exchange for the right to take rapid depreciation, for tax purposes, on the equipment. 3. Implicit taxes arise because the before-tax investment returns available on tax-favored assets are less than those available on tax-disfavored assets. Taxpayers wishing to obtain the tax-favored treatment offered by the investment bid up the price of the investment lowering the pre-tax rate of return. Tax clienteles arise because of variation across taxpayers in tax rates. Certain taxpayers are more likely than others to own various kinds of assets or to organize production in particular ways. Taxpayers facing similar marginal tax rates are attracted to the same investments because they offer the highest after- tax rate of return to these taxpayers. A firm that relies on long-term debt for financing likely faces a high marginal tax rate because the interest payments are tax deductible. Thus issuing debt to fund operations is tax efficient for high tax firms. The owners of distribution facilities (and other buildings and equipment) can deduct the cost of the assets (called depreciation) in calculating taxable income. These tax deductions are most valuable to high tax bracket taxpayers. If the tax depreciation schedule exceeds the rate of economic depreciation then the asset can be labeled as tax-favored and buyers are likely to compete for the asset bidding up the price (leading to the asset bearing implicit taxes). High tax rate taxpayers are the efficient owners of these types of assets. Leasing is often more efficient than buying for low tax bracket taxpayers. Thus if we look at the asset side, we might infer that ABC Corporation faces a low tax rate but when we look at the funding side of the economic balance sheet we might infer that ABC Corporation is a high tax rate corporation. Obviously both inferences cannot be right and thus it is likely that ABC Corporation is in the wrong clientele on one side of the balance sheet: if it is a low tax firm it should not have long-term debt outstanding. If it is a high-tax rate firm, it should not be leasing assets. (This solution focuses on the tax aspects of the problem – as we will learn in later chapters, there might be nontax reasons for the structure of the firm’s balance sheet, for example, nontax reasons for leasing.) 4. You would like to meet with the CEO so as to obtain information about the CEOs tax position, the rate at which the CEO can earn on her personal investments, and her preferences for current consumption (income) and current savings (deferred income). The CEO’s tax position depends not only on the salary from the firm but also any other income arising from her investments outside the firm. By knowing the CEO’s tax position, as well as the firm’s tax position, you can design a more tax efficient compensation package where efficiency includes the tax position of both parties. 8 Chapter 2 Tax Law Fundamentals Discussion Questions 1. a. False. While some tax rules written by Congress are written in the form of very specific restrictions that respond to particular abuses of the tax system that are experienced or anticipated, most tax rules lack the specificity necessary to eliminate ambiguity in the law. Given the enormous range of circumstances in which taxpayers can find themselves, the costs for Congress to pass legislation that is sufficiently comprehensive to cover all situations is greater than the benefits of greater clarity in the tax rules. b. False. Most tax legislation in the U.S. is initiated in the House. The Constitution (Article 1, Section 7, Clause 1) holds the House responsible for initiating revenue bills (although tax bills could be attached to other bills that originate in the Senate). c. True. Congress authorizes the Secretary of the Treasury to issue rules and regulations to enforce the Code. The primary purpose of the regulations is to explain and interpret particular sections of the Code. Regulations come in three types: (1) Legislative Regulations where Treasury has been given specific authority to issue a regulation pertaining to a particular section of the Code, (2) Interpretative Regulations that explain the meaning of a particular Code section and commit the Treasury and IRS (but not necessarily the courts) to a particular position, and (3) Procedural Regulations that explain issues such as the information that taxpayers must provide to the IRS and how the IRS is to conduct its affairs. While regulations are considered a direct extension of the lawmaking powers of Congress, revenue rulings are considered an application of the (more limited) administrative power of the IRS and thus have less authority. IRS rulings are also more limited in scope in that they are based on a specific set of facts. d. True. Revenue Rulings are published as official IRS policy while private letter rulings apply only to the taxpayer requesting the ruling and cannot be cited as precedent in a court of law. Still, private letter rulings are often considered carefully by taxpayers as clues to IRS policy. e. False. While the courts do not issue regulations per se, court decisions are a source of tax law and the IRS Commissioner is bound by legal precedents. 2. Appreciation in the price of assets is not taxed until the asset is sold (and income realized). When we apply this rule to investments in corporate stock, stock price appreciation is not taxed until the stock is sold and the gain is realized. This tax treatment encourages investors to buy and hold stock in corporations thus providing equity funds to corporations for their investment needs. However, some large stockholders in an effort to defer the taxation of the gains while at the same time obtaining cash undertake transactions known as “shorting against the box.” This strategy involves the taxpayer borrowing shares of stock equal to the number already owned and then selling the borrowed shares. The taxpayer then sells the borrowed shares thus realizing cash but no taxes are owed because there was no taxable gain on the shares sold. The loan is repaid at a later date by delivering the original appreciated stock. Delivery of the stock also triggers tax on the gain at this later date. The taxpayer has to pay interest on the value of the shares borrowed. It can be argued that this transaction serves no other purpose than to obtain cash today while deferring the taxes on the appreciated securities. 9 Chapter 2 Tax Law Fundamentals There are numerous other examples but serving no social purpose is a strict standard so one can think of many transactions that are designed to exploit the tax rules that have limited social purposes. 3. Basically see figure 2.1 and the accompanying text. 4. Greater specificity in the law can only be achieved at the higher cost of drafting and legislating. Moreover, where it is expensive for the taxing authority to monitor taxpayers' affairs closely (in other words, in the real world) specific rules can provide greater opportunities for taxpayers to structure their affairs in a way that exploits the rules. Greater specificity in the rules would also impose greater burdens on taxpayers and the taxing authority in learning what the relevant rules are. Once learned, however, greater specificity in the rules would give rise to fewer disputes between taxpayers and the tax collectors regarding tax liabilities. 5. These judicial doctrines discourage taxpayers from structuring their transactions to minimize taxes while not adhering to the social policy goals of the tax law. They allow the taxing authority to examine a transaction to determine if it has any motivation other than tax avoidance. If not, tax-favored treatment is imperiled. Unfortunately, such doctrines may also discourage socially desirable activities due to taxpayer concern over how the doctrine will be applied in practice. On the positive side, the doctrines also serve to discourage those transactions that are structured to appear, falsely, as contributing to the social goals that motivated the granting of tax-favored treatment to certain types of activities. 6. The Tax Code has multiple objectives: to redistribute wealth in the economy, to raise revenue, and to encourage (or discourage) desired economic activities. These multiple objectives naturally give rise to tax rates varying across different economic activities, tax rates varying across different individual taxpaying units, and tax rates varying for a given taxpaying unit over time. These differential tax rates, in turn, provide strong incentives for taxpayers to engage in tax planning. These incentives are the key ingredients that allow the tax system to be used to implement desired social policy. As an example, one economic activity that is encouraged is savings for retirement which is subsidized by the tax code in several ways (contributions are tax deductible and earnings in the pension fund are tax deferred until withdrawn in retirement). The wealthy are best placed to take advantage of these incentives. However the objective of redistributing wealth and raising revenue results in Congress placing limits on the deductibility of pension contributions both by amount and with phase outs based on adjusted gross income and filing status. Basically, Congress balances incentives against lost tax revenue and wealth redistribution giving rise to complexity in the code. As incentives are offered, taxpayers aggressively exploit the incentives to avoid taxes and as the tax revenue lost grows, Congress then introduces additional rules to “plug” the loopholes. Another cause of complexity is that the tax code allows legislators to allocate benefits in return for votes. Specific provisions are included for targeted groups of taxpayers. Both these causes of complexity (multiple objectives and vote gathering) are unlikely to be correctable. It is unlikely that Congress will forgo using the Tax Code to achieve multiple objectives and to forgo vote gathering via the code. 10 Chapter 2 Tax Law Fundamentals 7. Related parties whose interests do not conflict can afford (more than unrelated parties can) to enter into agreements that avoid stating explicitly in a contract the full nature of their transactions. Parties with opposing interests, who rely upon the law to enforce their claims, find such arrangements to be relatively unreliable. Tax laws discriminate against related-party contracts because it is easier for the parties to such contracts to engage in sham transactions designed to avoid taxes than is the case for parties contracting at arm’s length. Discriminating against related parties is not always in society’s best interests. The costs associated with enforcing and writing arm’s-length contracts can be significantly greater than those involving related parties. For example, a family business might be more efficient than a partnership or corporation comprised of unrelated parties because the mutual trust among family members can substitute for the detailed contracts that would have to be written, and the monitoring that would have to be undertaken, to ensure comparable outcomes. 8. Shifting income is beneficial when a high-tax-rate taxpayer can shift before-tax income to a low- tax-rate taxpayer. One way this could be effected is for the low-tax-rate taxpayer to “sell” the right to reduced taxes to the high-tax-rate individual by setting the terms of trade accordingly. In the case of related parties, the shifting income may be accomplished without a quid pro quo. Shifting income can be costly in that it typically requires a distortion in asset ownership or control; or it can give rise to distorted patterns of cash flows over time. For example, one way to shift income from high-income to low-income taxpayers is for high-income taxpayers to own tax-sheltered assets, like residential property, that are leased to low-income taxpayers. Another example is the formation of a partnership, where low-tax-rate taxpayers are allocated most of the annual income and high-tax-rate taxpayers are allocated most of the appreciation in the value of the partnership (to be realized on sale or liquidation of the partnership). In each example, the parties' incentives can be affected in unfortunate ways. In family tax planning, one might transfer income-producing assets to a child with the intention that the earnings will pay for the child’s education. A risk, however, is that the child may drop out of school and spend the money foolishly. Another way to transfer income to a low-tax-rate family member is by employing them in a family business. To the extent the family member is ill-suited to the job, such a strategy exacts an efficiency cost. Under the assignment-of-income doctrine, taxpayers must transfer an income-producing asset to a low-tax-rate taxpayer in order to shift taxable income. Costs arise from the high-tax-rate individual not being able to control what the low-tax-rate individual does with the assets. One way to mitigate these costs is to transfer the assets to a trust and have the trustee manage the assets in a pre-specified manner. 9. A national sales tax system would not eliminate all incentives to shift economic activities in ways that reduce taxes. Taxpayers would still have incentives to shift activities across periods to secure low- income household benefits as well as to exploit changes in sales tax rates across periods. Taxpayers would still have incentives to repackage goods into those that are granted tax exemption (shifting from one type of activity to another). And taxpayers would still have incentives to have consumption shifted from high-income to low-income “pockets” to secure reduced tax rates. The substance-over-form and business purpose doctrines would remain as important as ever in enforcing the tax law. 11 Chapter 2 Tax Law Fundamentals 10. Revenue rulings reduce taxpayer uncertainty regarding the tax treatment of particular transactions. Withholding such rulings can discourage taxpayers from entering into transactions that are granted tax-favored treatment. If the taxing authority wishes to maximize tax collections, withholding revenue rulings may be in its best interest even if it were costless to supply the rulings. Whether this is desirable, however, also depends on the social costs and benefits of the transactions that are discouraged. An additional cost of revenue rulings, of course, is the personnel cost required to do the research needed to provide the ruling. On the benefit side, revenue rulings can enhance the tax authority's ability to enforce the law by warning it of the types of transactions that taxpayers are contemplating entering into. Where the overall social costs to responding to ruling requests exceed the social benefits, charging a fee to the requesting taxpayer can align social and private costs and benefits better than a system in which there is no charge for such requests. 11. To the extent possible defer recognition of much income as possible until next year and accelerate as many deductions as possible to the current period. Deferral of income options: delay payment and receipt of any bonuses until the following tax year (the tax efficiency of this strategy depends on what is happening to the employer’s tax rate – if it is also expected to fall, then a careful analysis has to be undertaken – an example of multilateral tax planning.) Do not sell any appreciated assets or securities that give rise to taxable gains until next year. Shift stock portfolio from dividend paying stocks to non- dividend paying stocks to defer income until next period. The taxpayer has to be careful not to run afoul of the constructive receipts doctrine. This doctrine basically prevents taxpayers from turning their backs on income they have already earned and could collect easily. Examples include (1) interest credited on bank accounts where funds are available for withdrawal at any time, and (2) year-end paychecks that can be picked up at the payroll department. The Internal Revenue Service (IRS) has the authority to adjust a taxpayer’s method of accounting to ensure that it “clearly reflects income.” Most abuses of accounting methods involve postponing taxable income. Acceleration of deductions include making an extra mortgage payment at the end of the year qualifying the interest to be deductible in the current period, accelerating any elective medical procedures (provided the sum of the expenditures exceed the lower limit before they become deductible), and increasing to the extent possible any tax deductible personal pension contributions. 12. A flat tax system would not eliminate all incentives to shift economic activities in ways that reduce taxes. Taxpayers would still have incentives to shift activities across periods to defer taxation as well as to exploit changes in tax rates across periods. Taxpayers would still have incentives to restructure activities/transactions into those that are granted tax exemption (shifting from one type of activity to another, small businesses using lots of owner supplied debt – interest deductible to the firm but not taxable to the recipient). And taxpayers would still have incentives to shift income from high-income to low-income “pockets” (those family members with low income such that the high standard exemption reduces their tax bill to zero) to secure reduced tax rates. The substance-over-form and business purpose doctrines would remain as important as ever in enforcing the tax law. (The interested reader is referred to 12 Chapter 2 Tax Law Fundamentals an excellent in-depth analysis of tax planning under a flat tax by Michael Calegari, “Flat Taxes and Effective Tax Planning,” in National Tax Journal, December 1998, pp. 689-713.) And finally given the multiple objectives that Congress uses the Tax Code to pursue (to redistribute wealth in the economy, to raise revenue, and to encourage (or discourage) desired economic activities, as well as being use by individual legislators and the two major political parties to garner political support) we do not believe a flat tax with no itemized deductions is politically feasible in the U.S. Exercises 1. a. Pretax rate of return, R, = ($50,000-$100,000)/$100,000 = -50%. b. After-tax rate of return, r, = ) 70 . 1 ( 000 , 100 $ ) 28 . 1 ( 000 , 50 $ − − - 1 = 20%. (Explain your answer. Do you see any tax planning opportunities?) 2. a. If receive now and invest after-tax proceeds, the taxpayer will accumulate by the end of next period $100,000(1-t)(1+R(1-t)) = $100,000(1-.31)(1+.10(1-.31)) = $73,761. If defer receipt then after-tax will have $110,000(1-t) = $75,900. Thus defer receipt for one year. b. Equate the two alternatives and solve for R $100,000(1-t)(1+R(1-t)) = $110,000(1-t) 1+R(1-t) = 110,000/100,000 = 1.10 R = .10/(1-t) = .10/.69 = .1449 or 14.49%. (check by inserting R = .1449 in a). c. If receive now and invest after-tax proceeds, the taxpayer will accumulate by the end of next period $100,000(1-t 1 )(1+R(1-t 2 )) = $100,000(1-.31)(1+.10(1-.35)) = $73,485. If defer receipt then after-tax will have $110,000(1-t 2 ) = $110,000(1-.35) = $71,500. Thus take now, do not defer. d. Equate the 2 alternatives and solve for t 2 $100,000(1-.31)(1+R(1-t 2 )) = $110,000(1-t 2 ), $69,000(1+.10(1-t 2 )) = $110,000(1-t 2 ), 13
Study Now!
XY-Copilot AI
Unlimited Access
Secure Payment
Instant Access
24/7 Support
Document Chat
Document Details
Subject
Business Law